Economic calculation problem: Difference between revisions
mNo edit summary |
mNo edit summary |
||
(2 intermediate revisions by the same user not shown) | |||
Line 1: | Line 1: | ||
The '''economic calculation problem''' is a criticism of using [[economic planning]] as a substitute for [[Market (economics)|market-based]] allocation of the [[factors of production]]. It was first proposed by [[Ludwig von Mises]] in his 1920 article "[[Economic Calculation in the Socialist Commonwealth]]" and later expanded upon by [[Friedrich Hayek]]. F. A. Hayek, (1935), "The Nature and History of the Problem" and "The Present State of the Debate," in F. A. Hayek, ed. ''Collectivist Economic Planning'', pp. 1–40, 201–43. | The '''economic calculation problem''' is a criticism of using [[central economic planning]] as a substitute for [[Market (economics)|market-based]] allocation of the [[factors of production]]. It was first proposed by [[Ludwig von Mises]] in his 1920 article "[[Economic Calculation in the Socialist Commonwealth]]" and later expanded upon by [[Friedrich Hayek]]. F. A. Hayek, (1935), "The Nature and History of the Problem" and "The Present State of the Debate," in F. A. Hayek, ed. ''Collectivist Economic Planning'', pp. 1–40, 201–43. | ||
In his first article, Mises describes the nature of the price system under capitalism and describes how individual [[subjective value theory|subjective values]] are translated into the objective information necessary for [[Rational choice theory|rational]] allocation of resources in society.{{citation needed|date=May 2013}} | In his first article, Mises describes the nature of the price system under capitalism and describes how individual [[subjective value theory|subjective values]] are translated into the objective information necessary for [[Rational choice theory|rational]] allocation of resources in society.{{citation needed|date=May 2013}} | ||
In market exchanges, prices reflect the [[supply and demand]] of resources, labor and products. In his first article, Mises focused his criticism on the inevitable deficiencies of the [[Socialization (economics)|socialisation]] of capital goods, but Mises later went on to elaborate on various different forms of socialism in his book, ''[[Socialism (book)|Socialism]]''. Mises and Hayek argued that economic calculation is only possible by information provided through market prices, and that bureaucratic or technocratic methods of allocation lack methods to rationally allocate resources. The debate raged in the 1920s and 1930s, and that specific period of the debate has come to be known by [[Economic history|economic historians]] as ''The [[Socialist Calculation Debate]]''. Mises' initial criticism received multiple reactions and led to the conception of trial-and-error [[market socialism]], most notably the [[Lange–Lerner theorem]]. | In market exchanges, prices reflect the [[supply and demand]] of resources, labor and products. In his first article, Mises focused his criticism on the inevitable deficiencies of the [[Socialization (economics)|socialisation]] of capital goods, but Mises later went on to elaborate on various different forms of socialism in his book, ''[[Socialism (book)|Socialism]]''. Mises and Hayek argued that economic calculation is only possible by information provided through market prices, and that bureaucratic or technocratic methods of allocation lack methods to rationally allocate resources. The debate raged in the 1920s and 1930s, and that specific period of the debate has come to be known by [[Economic history|economic historians]] as ''The [[Socialist Calculation Debate]]''. Mises' initial criticism received multiple reactions and led to the conception of trial-and-error [[market socialism]], most notably the [[Lange–Lerner theorem]]. | ||
Mises argued in "Economic Calculation in the Socialist Commonwealth" that the pricing systems in socialist economies were necessarily deficient because if a public entity owned all the [[means of production]], no rational prices could be obtained for [[capital goods]] as they were merely internal transfers of goods and not "objects of exchange," unlike final goods. Therefore, they were unpriced and hence the system would be necessarily irrational, as the central planners would not know how to allocate the available resources efficiently. He wrote that "rational economic activity is impossible in a socialist [[commonwealth]]." Mises developed his critique of socialism more completely in his 1922 book ''Socialism: An Economic and Sociological Analysis'', arguing that the market price system is an expression of [[praxeology]] and can not be replicated by any form of bureaucracy. | |||
However, it is important to note that central planning has been criticized by socialists who advocated decentralized mechanisms of economic coordination, including [[Mutualism (economic theory)|mutualist]] [[Pierre-Joseph Proudhon]], [[Marxism|Marxist]] [[Leon Trotsky]], and [[Anarcho-communism|anarcho-communist]] [[Peter Kropotkin]] before the [[Austrian school]] critique. Central planning was later criticized by socialist economists such as [[Janos Kornai]] and [[Alec Nove]]. [[Robin Cox]] has argued that the economic calculation argument can only be successfully rebutted on the assumption that a moneyless socialist economy was to a large extent spontaneously ordered via a self-regulating system of stock control which would enable decision-makers to allocate production goods on the basis of their relative scarcity using calculation in kind. This was only feasible in an economy where most decisions were decentralised. Trotsky argued that central planners would not be able to respond effectively to local changes in the economy because they operate without meaningful input and participation by the millions of economic actors in the economy, and would therefore be an ineffective mechanism for coordinating economic activity. |
Latest revision as of 18:17, 26 December 2015
The economic calculation problem is a criticism of using central economic planning as a substitute for market-based allocation of the factors of production. It was first proposed by Ludwig von Mises in his 1920 article "Economic Calculation in the Socialist Commonwealth" and later expanded upon by Friedrich Hayek. F. A. Hayek, (1935), "The Nature and History of the Problem" and "The Present State of the Debate," in F. A. Hayek, ed. Collectivist Economic Planning, pp. 1–40, 201–43.
In his first article, Mises describes the nature of the price system under capitalism and describes how individual subjective values are translated into the objective information necessary for rational allocation of resources in society.[citation needed]
In market exchanges, prices reflect the supply and demand of resources, labor and products. In his first article, Mises focused his criticism on the inevitable deficiencies of the socialisation of capital goods, but Mises later went on to elaborate on various different forms of socialism in his book, Socialism. Mises and Hayek argued that economic calculation is only possible by information provided through market prices, and that bureaucratic or technocratic methods of allocation lack methods to rationally allocate resources. The debate raged in the 1920s and 1930s, and that specific period of the debate has come to be known by economic historians as The Socialist Calculation Debate. Mises' initial criticism received multiple reactions and led to the conception of trial-and-error market socialism, most notably the Lange–Lerner theorem.
Mises argued in "Economic Calculation in the Socialist Commonwealth" that the pricing systems in socialist economies were necessarily deficient because if a public entity owned all the means of production, no rational prices could be obtained for capital goods as they were merely internal transfers of goods and not "objects of exchange," unlike final goods. Therefore, they were unpriced and hence the system would be necessarily irrational, as the central planners would not know how to allocate the available resources efficiently. He wrote that "rational economic activity is impossible in a socialist commonwealth." Mises developed his critique of socialism more completely in his 1922 book Socialism: An Economic and Sociological Analysis, arguing that the market price system is an expression of praxeology and can not be replicated by any form of bureaucracy.
However, it is important to note that central planning has been criticized by socialists who advocated decentralized mechanisms of economic coordination, including mutualist Pierre-Joseph Proudhon, Marxist Leon Trotsky, and anarcho-communist Peter Kropotkin before the Austrian school critique. Central planning was later criticized by socialist economists such as Janos Kornai and Alec Nove. Robin Cox has argued that the economic calculation argument can only be successfully rebutted on the assumption that a moneyless socialist economy was to a large extent spontaneously ordered via a self-regulating system of stock control which would enable decision-makers to allocate production goods on the basis of their relative scarcity using calculation in kind. This was only feasible in an economy where most decisions were decentralised. Trotsky argued that central planners would not be able to respond effectively to local changes in the economy because they operate without meaningful input and participation by the millions of economic actors in the economy, and would therefore be an ineffective mechanism for coordinating economic activity.